terça-feira, 7 de maio de 2013
The German model is not for export
É sempre muito difícil exportar um modelo econômico, mas ele pode servir como inspiração para implementação de medidas adaptadas as condições de cada país. Este me parece ser o caso da relação de alguns países da zona do euro com o modelo alemão. Há mais virtude do que vicios no modelo alemão, o problema é que Wolf está mais focado nos últimos. Seu pessimismo em relação ao projeto da zona de euro é,em parte, justificado, mas, por outro lado, o levou a fazer previsões equivocadas sob o fim eminente deste importante experimento em política e economia.
Germany is reshaping the European economy in its own image. It is using its position as the largest economy and dominant creditor country to turn members of the eurozone into small replicas of itself – and the eurozone as a whole into a bigger one. This strategy will fail.
The Berlin consensus is in favour of stability-oriented policies: monetary policy should aim at price stability in the medium term; fiscal policy should aim at a balanced budget and low public debt. No whiff of Keynesian macroeconomic stabilisation should be admitted: that is the way to perdition.
To make this approach work, Germany has used shifts in its external balance to stabilise the economy: a rising surplus when domestic demand is weak, and the reverse. Germany’s economy may seem too big to rely on a mechanism characteristic of small and open economies. It has managed to do so, however, by relying upon its superb export-oriented manufacturing and ability to curb real wages. In the 2000s, this combination allowed the country to regenerate the current account surplus lost during the post-unification boom of the 1990s. This, in turn, helped bring modest growth, despite feeble domestic demand.
For this approach to stabilisation to work well, a large export-oriented economy also needs buoyant external markets. The financial bubbles of the 2000s helped deliver this. Between 2000 and 2007, Germany’s current account balance moved from a deficit of 1.7 per cent of gross domestic product to a surplus of 7.5 per cent. Meanwhile, offsetting deficits emerged elsewhere in the eurozone. By 2007, the current account deficit was 15 per cent of GDP in Greece, 10 per cent in Portugal and Spain, and 5 per cent in Ireland.
The domestic-demand counterparts of the huge external deficits run in these countries were mostly credit-fuelled private spending. Then came the global financial crisis. Capital inflows halted and private spending collapsed, creating huge fiscal deficits. Harvard’s Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff have shown that this was predictable. Between 2007 and 2009, the fiscal balance shifted from a surplus of 1.9 per cent of GDP to a deficit of 11.2 per cent in Spain, from a surplus of 0.1 per cent to a deficit of 13.9 per cent in Ireland, from a deficit of 3.2 per cent to one of 10.2 per cent in Portugal and from a deficit of 6.8 per cent to one of 15.6 per cent in Greece.
The mistaken consensus swiftly emerged, notably in Berlin, that this was a fiscal crisis. But that was to confuse symptoms with causes, except in the case of Greece. Yet, being deprived of access to the bond market or close to that plight, crisis-hit countries had to tighten, despite their deep recessions. Tighten they did. Between 2009 and 2012, according to the International Monetary Fund, the structural fiscal deficit shifted by 15.4 per cent of potential GDP in Greece, 5.1 per cent in Portugal, 4.4 per cent in Ireland, 3.8 per cent in Spain and 2.8 per cent in Italy. This combination of financial crises with fiscal tightening caused deep slumps: between the first quarter of 2008 and the fourth quarter of 2012, GDP fell 8.2 per cent in Portugal, 8.1 per cent in Italy, 6.5 per cent in Spain and 6.2 per cent in Ireland. So far, so grim.
Unfortunately, the eurozone’s healthier countries also hew tightly to the stability mantra. So they, too, tightened fiscal positions. The IMF forecasts that the eurozone’s cyclically adjusted fiscal deficit will shrink by 3.2 per cent of potential GDP between 2009 and 2013, to end up at just 1.1 per cent of GDP. The European Central Bank also continues to show next to no interest in spurring demand. Unsurprisingly, the eurozone economy is becalmed, with GDP at the same level in the fourth quarter of 2012 as it was in the third quarter of 2010.
Meanwhile, consumer price inflation is falling below the ECB’s 2 per cent target. Last week’s cut of a quarter of a percentage point in the intervention rate will make next to no difference. A big adverse shock risks turning low inflation into deflation. That would aggravate the pressure on countries in crisis. Even if deflation is avoided, the hope that they will grow their way out of their difficulties, via eurozone demand and internal rebalancing, is a fantasy, in the current macroeconomic context.
That leaves external adjustment. According to the IMF, France will be the only large eurozone member country to run a current account deficit this year. It forecasts that,
by 2018, every current eurozone member, except Finland, will be a net capital exporter. The eurozone as a whole is forecast to run a current account surplus of 2.5 per cent of GDP. Such reliance on balancing via external demand is what one would expect of a Germanic eurozone.
If one wants to understand how far the folly goes, one must study the European Commission’s work on macroeconomic imbalances. Its features are revealing. Thus, it takes a current account deficit of 4 per cent of GDP as a sign of imbalance. Yet, for surpluses, the criterion is 6 per cent. Is it an accident that this happens to be Germany’s? Above all, no account is taken of a country’s size in assessing its contribution to imbalances. In this way, Germany’s role is brushed out. Yet its surplus savings create huge difficulties when interest rates are close to zero. Its omission makes this analysis of “imbalances” close to indefensible.
The implications of the attempt to force the eurozone to mimic the path to adjustment taken by Germany in the 2000s are profound. For the eurozone it makes prolonged stagnation, particularly in the crisis-hit countries, highly likely. Moreover, if it starts to work, the euro is likely to move upwards, so increasing risks of deflation. Not least, the shift of the eurozone into surplus is a contractionary shock for the world economy. Who will be both able and willing to offset it?
The eurozone is not a small and open economy, but the second-largest in the world. It is too big and the external competitiveness of its weaker countries too frail to make big shifts in the external accounts a workable post-crisis strategy for economic adjustment and growth. The eurozone cannot hope to build a solid recovery on this, as Germany did in the buoyant 2000s. Once this is understood, the internal political pressures for a change in approach will surely become overwhelming.
Europe will not become a bigger Germany. It is foolish to believe it ever could. The eurozone will either achieve a better-balanced resolution of its difficulties or break up. Which of the two will it be? That remains the big unanswered question.
Martin Wolf
Fonte: FT